INTRODUCTION TO
MARKETING

Consumer Psychologist Facebook Forum

logo

Lars Perner, Ph.D.
Assistant Professor of Clinical Marketing
Department of Marketing
Marshall School of Business
University of Southern California
Los Angeles, CA 90089-1424, USA
(213) 740-7127

 

Pricing

Background.  Pricing decisions are extremely important for the firm.  Some of the reasons:

Conceptualizing price. A logical examination suggests that price should be defined as

                                          

That is, we need to consider the quantity you receive as well as the amount of money you have to fork out.  To say that gasoline costs $1.29 is meaningless outside the context that this cost is per gallon. 

WAYS TO CHANGE PRICE

The above conceptualization suggests that the marketer has several ways available to change price:

 

PRICING STRATEGIES

Pricing strategies can be categorized based on several different variables.  One variable of interest relates to the consistency of the prices.  Some retailers today attempt to follow a strategy of "everyday low pricing."  Although few firms tend to practice this method with perfect consistency, certain retailers like Wal-Mart tend to focus on providing constant low prices without any real sales.  Other retailers instead feature prices which, when not discounted, are somewhat higher.  To compensate, periodic sales feature price reductions.  Sales can be implemented either with a predictable pattern (e.g., a product is put on sale every fourth week) or in a random manner (e.g., in any given week, there is a 25% chance that the product will offered on sale).  (See chart on overheads).

Note that "high-low" and "everyday low price" strategies are intended to take advantage of different price elasticities across people.  Some consumers are price sensitive and will tend to buy only during sales; other people, in contrast, will buy all the time.  Thus, people who are not willing to switch brands will have to pay full price for your products when they are not on sale; while they are on sale, a large number of "switchers" are attracted and sales volumes are increased.

Another dimension of interest in pricing the price introductory strategy.  The "skimming" strategy entails offering a product first at a relatively high price.

Consider, for example, what we can do when there is a large degree of price elasticity—i.e., when some consumers are willing to pay more than others.  In the chart above, we see that some consumers are willing to pay a lot of money to get a new product quickly, while others are not willing to pay as much.  This often happens, for example, with new computer chips.  It may be possible, then, to charge the first segment more money, and then lower the price enough so that the next segment will buy it.  The process continues until all segments that can be profitably served have bought. In the chart below, we introduce the product at price P1. This means that we will only sell a limited quantity--Q1. Later, we reduce the price to P2, enabling us to sell a quantity of Q2. Eventually, we lower to P3, selling Q3.

Since consumers differ in how much they are willing to pay for a product, it is possible to make large margins on the price inelastic segment.  For example, Intel tends to charge high prices for its most recent chips, gradually lowering prices as a new generation is introduced.

Alternatively, firms may choose to use the "penetration" pricing strategy.  This strategy also takes advantage of price elasticity and attempts to dramatically boost the number of units sold by offering the product at a low price. 

Since costs of production tend to go down as cumulative production increases, this strategy may be effective.  Penetration pricing is also useful when a firm wishes to establish a large market share early on, and it may be useful to develop a market for accessories to products.  For example, a manufacturer of a new computer system may want to increase sales volumes in order to encourage the development of compatible software so that the computer brand will become more competitively attractive.

Note that "skimming" and penetration pricing involve tradeoffs.  A clearly preferred strategy may not be obvious, and managers may need to engage in some serious consideration to arrive at a desired strategy.  Both strategies involve some level of risk.  The main risk to "skimming" is the attraction of aggressive competitors who see an opportunity to make large profits by entering.  Penetration pricing, in contrast, gambles on the possibility that sales volumes will in fact increase with lower prices.

Two other concepts are worth noting.  A "cost-plus" pricing strategy entails marking up the estimated cost of producing a product by a certain, fixed percentage.  We will discuss deficiencies of this approach later.  In contrast, pricing based on consumer perceived value keeps the firm in closer proximity to the market.

Several objectives can be pursued in pricing.  One is product line pricing.  In some cases, it may be useful to settle for small margins on some members of the product line in order to assure the success of others.  For example, Avery, the maker of adhesive labels, sells relatively inexpensive software for printing on the labels in order to stimulate demand for the higher margin labels.  Two-tier pricing involves an attempt to entice the consumer into buying a product at a low price with the expectation that he or she will buy accessories later.  For example, makers of razor blades tend to sell the razors at low prices so that the consumer has an incentive to go with the same brand of blades later on.  Tying, which is often illegal in the U.S. when it is based on unreasonable exercise of monopoly power by a dominant firm in a market, involves requiring the consumer to buy a less desirable product in order to be able to buy a more desired one.  Back when Xerox was the dominant manufacturer of copy machines, for example, a court case forced the company to abandon its policy of including service of the copiers with machine purchase; consumers were now free to seek out any cheaper third party service available.  For a more contemporary example, let's imagine that rap singer Joyoys J has two albums on the market:  A Rated X-Mas and X-Mas Gift 'rappin'.  If market research suggests that X-Mas Gift 'rapping' will be received as a mediocre album while A Rated X-mas is likely to reach Platinum status,  Joyoys J might refuse to sell A Rated X-Mas without a simultaneous purchase of the less desirable product.  The legal issues here are complex, in part because there are often serious questions about the extent to which it is reasonable for the customer to be able to buy only one product when most customers would want to buy the combination.  It is probably not reasonable, for example, to insist on being allowed to buy only pink M&Ms® since most customers appear to prefer a mix of colors. 

Product price bundling, generally legal, presents an alternative to outright tying.  Here, the consumer can buy each product separately, but a discount is offered for buying two or more items simultaneously.  In Joyoys J’s case, a  possible pricing schedule might be:

A Rated X-mas                           $20.00
X-Mas Gift 'rapping'                    $10.00
Both for                                    $25.00 (>$20.00+$10.00=$30.00)

In general, simple "cost-plus" pricing is inappropriate because:

Cost should, however, play some role in pricing decisions:

 

CONSUMER PRICE AWARENESS

Research suggests a large segment of consumers does not give much attention to the prices of individual products.  Consumers were found on the average to spend only about 12 seconds between arriving at the site within a store where a frequently purchased product was located and departing; on the average, consumers inspected only 1.2 products.  Only 55.6%, seconds after having selected a product, could specify its price within 5% of accuracy.  Note that this study does not indicate a total lack of consumer price sensitivity since consumers are undoubtedly making some inferences about the overall price levels of a store.  Thus, the store has some incentive to maintain reasonable overall prices.

COMPETITION AND ANTITRUST ISSUES IN PRICING

The United States maintains relatively stringent (by international standards) antitrust laws.  Much of the rest of the World is catching up with us, but traditionally, anti-competitive laws in many European and Asian countries were either non-existent, intended to actively encourage collusion, or not enforced.  In fact, a professor at INSEAD, the premier French business school, reported that his students—who came from countries throughout Europe—actually expected him to teach them how to collude with each other.  Antitrust issues relevant to prices can be categorized into the following main categories:

CONSUMER REFERENCE PRICES

Consumers typically maintain reference prices for products.  These are typically based on prices they have seen or paid in the past or perceived fairness of prices. 

There are two kinds of reference prices:

Research shows that both experience (prices previously paid) and the sale context (prices of competing brands) influence a consumer's internal reference price.

Consumers tend to experience two sources of value for a product.  Acquisition utility refers to the utility of obtaining a product, while transaction utility refers to the difference between a subject's reference price and the featured price.

Traditionally, managers have believed that you need to approach a certain threshold of some 15-20% discount before consumers will respond significantly to sales.  More recent research, however, shows that a large segment of the population will apparently respond to "negligible" discounts.  For example, if a product is reduced in price from $3.98 to $3.96 (a "whopping" one half of one percent price cut!), a large number of consumers will "bite."  A store manager similarly found that just placing a sign saying "EVERYDAY LOW PRICE" randomly among store products increased sales of the affected products by some 20%.

There is some question as to whether "odd" product prices (those ending in "9," "95," or "99) actually increase sales.  Some effect has been found in the U.S., but no effect was found in Germany.  Note, however, that "odd" prices may communicate the idea that you are receiving a bargain, which may nor may not be consistent with the desired positioning of the product.

As some firms have painfully learned, changing the price of a product can be difficult.  Some experimenters tried to introduce a laundry detergent both at a "high" and "low" price in stores.  After eight weeks, the price of the laundry detergent under the "low" intro price condition was changed to match that of the "high" introductory condition. 

Although sales were higher in the low introductory price condition while the price was low, sales dropped dramatically after the price had been raised—in fact, after sixteen weeks, cumulative sales were higher in those stores where the price had been high all along.  This suggests that consumers started thinking about the product as a "low price" one and had difficulty adjusting when the price was later changed.

There are other cases where changing product prices has proven difficult.  In the 1970s, consumers were reluctant to pay above an effective $2.00 "ceiling" for cereal.  The Coca Cola Company also found it difficult to raise its price above its highly salient 5 cent level.

The "framing" of products tends to dramatically influence consumer response.  The Automobile Club of Southern California, for example, indicates that upgrading to "AAA Plus" service costs "only pennies a day" rather than emphasizing the yearly cost.  Note that this framing effect may also have implications for the practice of sales—when the sale is retracted, consumers may see this as a loss rather than the termination of a gain.

 

MANUFACTURER VS. RETAILER PRICING INTERESTS

Retailers and manufacturers often have conflicting interests since:

 

ADVERTISING:  DOES IT INCREASE OR DECREASE PRICE ELASTICITY?

Economists such as John Kenneth Galbraith have traditionally held that advertising serves to create artificial differentiation among products where few real differences exist and thus allows the firm to charge higher prices.  This effect can be observed on whole-sale prices, where heavily advertised products tend to sell for higher prices.

Research shows, however, that advertising may have the opposite effect on prices at the retail level.  Retailers will often use highly advertised products as loss leaders, and thus advertising may depress retail prices of products.  It has also been found that prices of eye-glasses are lower in those states that allow advertising (containing price information), and after deregulation, air fares were negatively correlated with advertising on the route in question (again making prices more readily comparable).